Economic Geography
Confronting economics and economists
Download 3.2 Kb. Pdf ko'rish
|
Economic and social geography
Confronting economics and economists
To understand how activism and public engagement came to be a more or less normal part of my cohort’s experience, it is essential to understand the peculiar moment of the 1980s and the position of the field of economics in public policy in the United States (as distinct from the United Kingdom). Today when I go to policy meetings it is exceedingly rare to find a political scientist, or sociologist or planner, and it is even rarer to find a geographer. Today, in the United States, neoclassically trained economists have a lock on policy discourse. This was not always the case. In the 1980s, neoclassical economics was not monolithic. In some circles that world-view was being called into question. In the 1980s, an era of unprecedented industrial restructuring, ‘legitimate’ critics from the left, center and right challenged status quo explana- tions for the nation’s economic woes. In fact, it was an incredible moment when the likes of Bennett Harrison and Barry Bluestone, and less controversial figures such as Lester Thurow (Thurow 1981, 1984, 1985a, 1985b, 1993; Thurow and Tyson 1987), Robert Reich and Ira Magaziner, Wall Street investment banker Felix Rohaytn and political scientist Chalmers Johnson of University College Berkeley, coalesced around a set of arguments that raised the spectre of failure in the United States model of market capitalism (Johnson 1982, 1984, 1987; Johnson et al. 1989; Magaziner and Reich 1983). The Japanese and the emergent Asian Tigers were encroaching upon United States industries such as autos, computers, and clothing, and thumping national firms. Other models of capi- talist development were not just curiosities, but instead were discussed as compet- ing alternatives to the United States system of market capitalism. The failure of the United States system was increasingly being laid at the feet of United States corporatism. A whole new debate unfolded about whether America should pursue industrial strategies to maintain its competitiveness. Berkeley professors and the Berkeley Roundtable on the International Economy, an influential university-based think tank, were important influences on and somewhat ‘neoliberal’ voices in the late 1980s. While more concerned about the social consequences of change, many students were funded through the Berkeley Round Table on the International Economy (BRIE) and represented in effect an institutionalization of what look- ing back must be now considered a pretty radical conversation (see, e.g. Johnson 1982, 1984, 1987; Johnson et al. 1989; Tyson 1992; Zysman and Tyson 1983). 210 Amy K. Glasmeier With a Democratically-controlled Congress and a Federal agency apparatus populated by liberal social scientists, a moment of self-doubt and indecision descended upon the economic policy establishment. Questions were being raised about whether there was a better way to organize the economy and society. In this conceptualism there was a positive and active role for the state combined with the greater involvement of citizens and local organizations. Admittedly, the one weakness of the time was the failure to articulate a comprehensive and action- able alternative to 1950s Keynesianism. The diagnosis of the problem was only one of the steps required to mend the national economic condition. This unique moment allowed a range of voices to be heard, among them geographers, planners and more institutionally minded economists. Becoming an academic during this time was easily coupled with a belief that a person could make a difference and could profitably contribute to policy discussions. Download 3.2 Kb. Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: |
Ma'lumotlar bazasi mualliflik huquqi bilan himoyalangan ©fayllar.org 2024
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling