Economic Geography
Download 3.2 Kb. Pdf ko'rish
|
Economic and social geography
Political economy
Political economy perspectives, in the sense of Marx rather than the Milton Friedman School favored in mainstream economics, emerged in the 1970s. Early proponents had abandoned location theory, convinced that capitalist market mechanisms could never deliver the social equity that they had sought (in the furore of post-1945 social engineering). Under the echoes of 1968, these critiques galvanized a new generation of economic geographers. Just as Lösch turned to the capitalist market to redress the evils of Nazism, so Harvey (1982) turned to socialism to redress the evils of capitalism. Drawing heavily on Marx (whose arguments can be as deductive-analytical as those of mainstream economics, Roemer 1981), Harvey shows that economic inequality is inevitable because production under capitalism entails the exploitation of one class by another. Furthermore, the geography of capitalist production is bound up with uneven development and spatial divisions of labor that create geographical inequalities (e.g. dividing workers and capitalists in core regions from workers in the periphery). Capitalism is conceptualized as riven with social and geographical conflicts and contradictions that make any equilibrium at best serendipitous and temporary. Capitalism lurches from one crisis to another, with its trajectories shaped by class and spatial struggle and by the unintended consequences of The economic geography project 13 economic choices and political strategies. Here, the ‘economic’ is centered on capitalist commodity production (the realization and accumulation of profits, and their investment in new production) rather than simply on market exchange. Geography matters for two reasons. First, as for Lösch, space trumps economic theory. The barriers that space poses to the rapid realization of profits on capital invested in commodity production (in the form of both the built environment and the geography of communication) require modifications to Marx’ theories of value, class and crisis (Harvey 1982; Massey 1984; Scott 1980; Sheppard and Barnes 1990; Webber and Rigby 1996). Second, nature constrains the impera- tive to accumulate and grow that is at the center of capitalist commodity produc- tion (Smith 1984). Both nature and the spatial organization of production are dialectically related to capitalism: they are shaped by, but also shape, its evolution. In this view, social movements have limited influence and unequal livelihood chances are best redressed by replacing capitalism, although little normative or empirical analysis of livelihood possibilities under more collective modes of production has been undertaken. During the 1990s political economy came to be dominated by regulation theory. Seeking to understand capitalism’s resilience, geographers sought to understand the transition from Fordism to post-Fordism and neoliberalism. Of Download 3.2 Kb. Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: |
Ma'lumotlar bazasi mualliflik huquqi bilan himoyalangan ©fayllar.org 2024
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling