Scandinavian Economic History Review issn: 0358-5522 (Print) 1750-2837 (Online) Journal homepage
Download 1.56 Mb.
|
Article 2
on coffee and tobacco did not mean lower import levels, but rather a slow increase between 1830 and 1864. The impact of the sugar tariff is a bit more difficult to interpret, but it rather seems that lower tariffs meant higher revenue. Or simply that the import of sugar continued to increase regardless of the tariff; it increased when it was stable, lowered, and increased. Hence, Swedish policymakers seem to have set tariffs that were fiscally efficient during the 1840s, 1850s, and 1860s.17
16 H. HÄGGQVIST relationship was also there when the three tariffs from Figure 8 was measured against customs rev-enue on those three goods, with a correlation coefficient of 0.83(see Figure 11). The relationship is still positive when the tariffs are measured as ad valorem, but it is weaker at 0.41. Increases in nom-inal tariffs seem to have had a positive impact on real increases in customs revenue, both on total level and on the three most important commodities. This was less so when prices were taken into account, but there was still a positive relationship on sectoral level. There is some indication that the government was able to raise fiscal tariffs on good with lower elasticity of demand and increase revenue as a result. 6. Conclusions This article has set out to answer what determined the growth of customs revenue in nine-teenth century Sweden. It has focused on tariff setting and the structure of customs revenue in order to answer this question. Integral changes were made to Swedish trade policy during the period, and many were undertaken before 1860. This article has shown that these changes need to be taken into account to properly analyse the fiscal development in nineteenth century Sweden, something which has typically been lacking in earlier research such as Gårestad (1985) and Henrekson and Stenkula (2015). First, the general development of Swedish nineteenth cen-tury trade policy served fiscal needs and goals. The move away from taxing exports to taxing only imports, and mainly imports whose growth were not hurt by the existence of tariffs, was instrumental in securing a steady flow of customs revenue. Not only was this likely a move that promoted export growth, but imports would come to outgrow exports during the second half of the century, and some decades even outgrew GDP. Taxes on imports hence created room for revenue growth that taxes on all of foreign trade could not. The several consecutive decisions to remove import bans and replace them with (often rather high) tariffs served the same purpose. Second, the liberalisation of trade policy during the 1850s forced a slimmer tariff structure that put fiscal burden on a smaller number of goods. These were particularly goods with low elas-ticity of demand, such as sugar, coffee, tobacco, and alcohol. This puts Sweden along the same lines of other European countries who also taxed these goods highly for revenue purposes. Cer-tain items which were important in the revenue baskets of other countries, such as petroleum and oils, were however only of minor or no importance in Sweden. Sweden instead stood out by drawing lots of revenue from textiles and clothing, and during 1890–1910 also from capital goods. Revenue from agricultural goods, mostly wheat, also became relevant again when these tariffs were reinstated during the 1880s. Third, the rates on these types of goods could be increased at times when that was deemed necessary without losing revenue. Rather, the analysis in section 5 showed that revenue increased when tariff rates were heightened. The result that higher tariffs yielded higher revenues is interesting in relation to that issue as raised by Irwin (1998). This development took place during a critical time when customs revenue as share of total government revenue really took off and came to be the single most important tax receipt. Trade policy hence came to be a key driver of nineteenth century fiscal develop-ment in Sweden. Revenue needs were a large driver of tariff policy in nineteenth century Sweden. This contrasts with earlier Swedish research (Heckscher, 1954; Jonsson, 2005; Montgomery, 1921) but rhymes well with international research and experiences in other countries (see for example Williamson, 2006, and the cited work in Dormois et al., 2006). Tariffs could be set without discouraging imports and decreasing revenue, but as earlier research has pointed out, tariffs could have had other negative effects not discussed here. This was probably most likely towards the end of the period here when more customs revenue came from seemingly protective duties (on agriculture and industrial imports) than before. The state benefited in terms of growing revenue, but industry and agriculture could have suffered under a higher tariff burden. One can however wonder whether the actual effects were leaned towards the fiscal or the protectionist. An import like wheat grew after agricultural tariffs SCANDINAVIAN ECONOMIC HISTORY REVIEW 17 were re-introduced and arguably came to function like a commodity with low elasticity of demand. Is it possible that tariffs served both fiscal and protectionist needs at the same time or are these mutually exclusive? This possible trade policy clash warrants further studies. Acknowledgement An early version of the paper was presented at the 41st Annual Economic and Business History Society Conference, Montreal, Canada. The author wishes to thank the participants there for helpful comments. Thank you to Peter Hed-berg for reading the text and advising how to approve the approach and the analysis. I am very thankful for the con-structive comments and criticism from editor Jari Ojala and two anonymous referees. All remaining errors and misunderstandings are the sole responsibility of the author. Disclosure statement No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author. Funding This work was supported by the Jan Wallanders och Tom Hedelius Stiftelse samt Tore Browaldhs Stiftelse [grant num-ber P2016-0135:1]. ORCID Henric Häggqvist http://orcid.org/0000-0003-1245-0511 References Official reports Kommerskollegium. (1899). Arbetsstatistik A01. Undersökning af bagerierna i Sverige 1897. Retrieved from https:// www.scb.se/H/C396vrig20STATISTIK20frC3a5n20ANDRA20myndigheter201877-/ ARBETSSTATISTIK20utg.20AV20Kommerskollegium%201899-1913/Arbetsstatistik-A01-Undersokning-bagerierna- Sverige-1897.pdf SOU. (1924:37). Betänkande angående tullsystemets verkningar i Sverige före världskriget (Vol. 1). Retrieved from http://regina.kb.se/sou/ Official statistics Bidrag till Sveriges Officiella Statistik (BiSOS), serie F, Utrikes handel och sjöfart, 1834–1910. [online for the years 1858–1910]. Retrieved from https://www.scb.se/sv_/hitta-statistik/historisk-statistik/sok-publikationer-efter-amne/ Generaltullstyrelsens sammandrag över Sveriges import och export 1819–1831. Retrieved from https://www.scb.se/ sv_/hitta-statistik/historisk-statistik/sok-publikationer-efter-amne/ Statistisk årsbok för Sverige (SOS). (1914). Retrieved from https://www.scb.se/sv_/hitta-statistik/historisk-statistik/ sok-publikationer-efter-amne/ Svensk Författningssamling (SFS). Literature Bohlin, J. (2005). Tariff protection in Sweden, 1885–1914. Scandinavian Economic History Review, 53(2), 7–29. Bulmer-Thomas, V. (2013). The economic history of Latin America since independence. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Cardoso, J. L., & Lains, P. (2010a). Introduction: Paying for the liberal state. In J. L. Cardoso & P. Lains (Eds.), Paying for the liberal state: The rise of public finance in nineteenth-century Europe (pp. 1–27). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Cardoso, J. L., & Lains, P. (2010b). Public finance in Portugal, 1796–1910. In J. L. Cardoso & P. Lains (Eds.), Paying for the liberal state: The rise of public finance in nineteenth-century Europe (pp. 251–278). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Centeno, M. A. (2002). Blood and debt : War and the nation-state in Latin America. University Park, PA: Pennsylvania State University Press. Coatsworth, J. H., & Williamson, J. G. (1999). Always protectionist? Latin American tariffs from independence to great depression. Journal of Latin American Studies, 36(2), 205–232. 18 H. HÄGGQVIST Comín, F. (2010). Public finance and the rise of the liberal state in Spain, 1808–1914. In J. L. Cardoso & P. Lains (Eds.), Paying for the liberal state: The rise of public finance in nineteenth-century Europe (pp. 214–250). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Dakhlia, S., & Nye, J. V. C. (2004). Tax Britannica: Nineteenth century tariffs and British national income. Public Choice, 121(3), 309–333. Daunton, M. (2010). Creating legitimacy: Administering taxation in Britain, 1815–1914. In J. L. Cardoso & P. Lains (Eds.), Paying for the liberal state: The rise of public finance in nineteenth-century Europe (pp. 27–56). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Dedinger, B. (2006). From virtual free-trade to virtual protectionism: Or, did protectionism have any part in Germany’s rise to commercial power 1850–1913? In J.-P. Dormois & P. Lains (Eds.), Classical trade protectionism 1815–1914 (pp. 219–241). Abingdon: Routledge. Dormois, J.-P., Foreman-Peck, J., & Lains, P. (2006). Introduction. In J.-P. Dormois & P. Lains (Eds.), Classical trade protectionism 1815–1914 (pp. 1–9). Abingdon: Routledge. Edvinsson, R., & Söderberg, J. (2010). The evolution of Swedish consumer prices, 1290–2008. In R. Edvinsson, T. Jacobson, & D. Waldenström (Eds.), Exchange rates, prices, and wages, 1277–2008 (pp. 412–452). Stockholm: Ekerlids förlag. Eloranta, J. (2007). From the great illusion to the great War: Military spending behaviour of the great powers, 1870– 1913. European Review of Economic History, 11(2), 255–283. Federico, G. (2006). Protection and Italian economic development: Much ado about nothing. In J.-P. Dormois & P. Lains (Eds.), Classical trade protectionism 1815–1914 (pp. 193–218). Abingdon: Routledge. Federico, G., & Tena-Junguito, A. (2017). A tale of two globalizations: Gains from trade and openness 1800–2010. Review of World Economics, 153(3), 601–626. Findlay, R., & O’Rourke, K. H. (2007). Power and plenty: Trade, war, and the world economy in the second millennium. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Fregert, K., & Gustafsson, R. (2014). Fiscal statistics for Sweden, 1670–2011. In R. Edvinsson, T. Jacobson, & D. Waldenström (Eds.), House prices, stock returns, national accounts, and the Riksbank balance sheet, 1620–2012 (pp. 183–222). Stockholm: Ekerlids Förlag. Gårestad, P. (1985). Industrialisering och beskattning i Sverige 1861–1914 [Industrialization and taxation in Sweden 1861–1914]. Uppsala: University of Uppsala. Gerentz, S. (1951). Kommerskollegium och näringslivet: Minnesskrift. Stockholm: Kommerskollegium. Häggqvist, H. (2015). On the ocean of protectionism: The structure of Swedish tariffs and trade 1780–1830. Uppsala: Acta Universitatis Upsaliensis. Heckscher, E. F. (1954). An economic history of Sweden. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Hedberg, P., & Häggqvist, H. (2018). Wartime trade and tariffs in Sweden from the Napoleonic Wars to WWI. In J. Eloranta, E. Golson, P. Hedberg, & C. Moreira (Eds.), Small and medium powers in global history: Trade, conflicts and neutrality from the 18th to the 20th centuries (pp. 116–138). London: Routledge. Hedberg, P., & Karlsson, L. (2015). Neutral trade in time of war: The case of Sweden, 1838–1960. International Journal of Maritime History, 27(1), 61–78. Henrekson, M., & Stenkula, M. (2015). Swedish taxation since 1862: An introduction and overview. In M. Henrekson M. Stenkula (Eds.), Swedish taxation: Developments since 1862 (pp. 1–33). New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan. Hinrichs, H. H. (1965). Determinants of government revenue shares among less-developed countries. The Economic Journal, 75, 546–556. Hinrichs, H. H. (1966). A general theory of tax structure change during economic development. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University. Hoekman, B. M., & Kostecki, M. M. (2001). The political economy of the world trading system: The WTO and beyond. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Hultqvist, P. (1955). Försvar och skatter: studier i svensk riksdagspolitik från representationsreformen till kompromissen 1873. Göteborg: University of Gothenburg. Irwin, D. A. (1993). Free trade and protection in nineteenth-century Britain and France revisited: A comment on Nye. The Journal of Economic History, 53(1), 146–152. Irwin, D. A. (1998). Higher tariffs, lower revenues? Analyzing the fiscal aspects of “The great tariff debate of 1888”. The Journal of Economic History, 58(1), 59–72. Jonsson, P. (2005). Handelsfrihetens vänner och förbuden: Identitet och politisk kommunikation i svensk tullpolitik 1823–1854. Örebro: Örebro universitetsbibliotek. Jörberg, L. (1972). A history of prices in Sweden 1732–1914: Sources, methods, tables (Vol. 1). Lund: Gleerup. Lains, P. (2006). Protectionism and Portuguese industrialisation. In J.-P. Dormois & P. Lains (Eds.), Classical trade protectionism 1815–1914 (pp. 242–264). Abingdon: Routledge. Magnusson, L. (2009). Nation, state and the industrial revolution : The visible hand. New York, NY: Routledge. Mathias, P., & O’Brien, P. K. (1978). Taxation in England and France 1715–1810. Journal of European Economic History, 5(3), 601–650. SCANDINAVIAN ECONOMIC HISTORY REVIEW 19 McLean, I. (2001). Irish potatoes, Indian corn and British policies: Interests, ideology, heresthetic and the repeal of the corn laws. In F. McGillivray, I. McLean, R. Pahre, & C. Schonhardt-Bailey (Eds.), International trade and political institutions: Instituting trade in the long nineteenth century (pp. 99–145). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Mitchell, B. R. (2003a). International historical statistics: Europe, 1750–2000. New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan. Mitchell, B. R. (2003b). International historical statistics: The Americas, 1750–2000. New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan. Montgomery, A. (1921). Svensk tullpolitik 1816–1911. Stockholm: Isaac Marcus boktryckeri AB. Nye, J. V. C. (2007). War, wine, and taxes: The political economy of Anglo-French trade, 1689–1900. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. O’Rourke, K. H. (1997). The European grain invasion, 1870–1913. The Journal of Economic History, 57(4), 775–801. O’Rourke, K. H., & Williamson, J. G. (1999). Globalization and history : The evolution of a nineteenth-century Atlantic economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. O’Rourke, K. H., de la Escosura, L. P., & Daudin, G. (2010). Trade and empire. The Cambridge Economic History of Modern Europe, 2, 96–121. Prasad, M. (2012). The land of too much: American abundance and the paradox of poverty. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Rodriguez, E. (1980). Offentlig inkomstexpansion: en analys av drivkrafterna bakom de offentliga inkomsternas utveck- ling i Sverige under 1900-talet. Lund: Gleerup. Schön, L. (2010). The rise of the fiscal state in Sweden, 1800–1914. In J. L. Cardoso & P. Lains (Eds.), Paying for the liberal state: The rise of public finance in nineteenth-century Europe (pp. 162–185). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Schön, L., & Krantz, O. (2012). Swedish historical national accounts 1560–2010. Retrieved from https://www.ekh.lu.se/ en/research/economic-history-data/lu-madd/shna1560-2010_2012 Schremmer, D. E. (1989). Taxation and public finance: Britain, France, and Germany. The Cambridge Economic History of Europe, 8, 315–494. Stenkula, M. (2014). Swedish taxation in a 150-year perspective. Nordic Tax Journal, 2014(2), 10–42. Stenkula, M. (2015). Taxation of goods and services in Sweden (1862–2013). In M. Henrekson & M. Stenkula (Eds.), Swedish taxation: Developments since 1862 (pp. 179–221). New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan. Tarschys, D. (1988). Tributes, tariffs, taxes and trade: The changing sources of government revenue. British Journal of Political Science, 18(1), 1–20. Tena-Junguito, A. (2006). Assessing the protectionist intensity of tariffs in nineteenth century European trade policy. In J.-P. Dormois & P. Lains (Eds.), Classical trade protectionism 1815–1914 (pp. 99–120). Abingdon: Routledge. Widell, L. (1900). Sveriges finanser under senare hälften af 1880-talet: ett försök till en allmän svensk finansstatistik. 1. Lund: Gleerup. Williamson, J. G. (2006). Explaining world tariffs, 1870–1913: Stolper-Samuelson, strategic tariffs, and state revenues. In R. Findlay, R. G. H. Henriksson, H. Lindgren, & M. Lundahl (Eds.), Eli Heckscher, international trade, and econ-omic history (pp. 199–328). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Williamson, J. G. (2011). Trade and poverty: When the third world fell behind. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Download 1.56 Mb. Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: |
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling