Centre for Economic Policy Research
Session 2: Auditors and rating agencies
Download 1.95 Mb. Pdf ko'rish
|
geneva5
Session 2: Auditors and rating agencies
Edward J Kane Boston College According to Ed Kane the key word in this debate is ‘disinformation’. The issue is to get disinformation out of what is called the information flow. Disinformation is not just misinformation but information that has been cleverly designed to persuade people that adverse developments will not occur. The issue is then how hard the watchdogs dig to find the disinformation and to what extent they are willing to keep things to themselves. In truth, incentives for revealing disinfor- mation are weak. The premise of the Report is that corporate managers, accountants and credit rating agencies are responsible to all stakeholders, but feel no compunction to treat all interests equally, especially in the short run. The first line of defence has to be the personal ethics of the watchdogs and the people being watched. A common belief is that the trade-off between feeling good about the cleverness of exploiting others and the sense of shame for doing it has worsened over time. The second line of defence is the watchdogs, who must be known for both barking and biting. The concern is that the bark of the watchdogs is much greater than their bite. The importance of auditors has already been stressed; that of rating agencies is to provide an outside check on the reliability and economic meaning of the information that rating agencies produce. Auditors and rating agencies are subject to bias and coercion, euphemistically called conflicts of interest in the Report. Formal standards of accountability for estimates produced by both types of firms are incomplete and statistically shallow. The next question, therefore, is to ask what the internal and external watch- dogs really do. Internally, a firm’s board of directors and auditing team have a duty to impose sound reporting safeguards and to detect deviations from these standards. This duty is not adequately performed in many cases and this is why external watchdogs are needed. External watchdogs include outside auditors, stock analysts, credit-rating agencies, standard-setting professional organizations, regulators, government examiners, law-enforcement personnel and information media (the ‘press’). The first session emphasized the force of reputational penal- ties for watchdog dishonesty. These penalties can be overcome if insiders can temporarily deflect market prices from their full-information or ‘inside’ value through deceptive accounting reporting. Counterincentives can be created against disinformation activity through compensation that lets insiders and formally ‘independent’ external watchdogs profit extravagantly from temporarily boosting a firm’s accounting condition or performance. In principle, watchdog institutions that have no kinship ties to, or important commercial dealings with, insiders help outside investors to identify and ignore disinformation. In practice, however, managers can and do increase their firm’s perceived profitability by concealing unfavourable information, and watchdogs are often fooled or persuaded to cooperate in the concealment. Accountants are also persuaded to participate by earning substantial profits from certifying loophole-ridden measurements that temporarily conceal adverse developments from outside stakeholders. Similarly credit-rating agencies can earn handsome fees for not challenging accounting information reported by contractual clients as Discussion and Roundtables 89 conscientiously as figures reported by other firms. The ethics of watchdog profes- sions limit their accountability for producing ‘unsafe’ informational products. The major weakness in the information production system lies in the link between the internal corporate governance of firms and the ethics of the watchdogs. The profession needs new codes to take away some of the protection that they have in courts to lessen the temptation of selling and cooperating in disinformation. The major problem is the narrow defence that is provided by the so-called ‘safe-harbours loophole’. The Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 continues to assume that the formal independence of watchdogs is key to reliable authentication. The Act ignores the dangers of leaving US accounting rules riddled with safe-harbour loopholes. The Act asymmetrically imposes stronger disclosure obligations on CEOs, CFOs, attorneys and investment analysts but not on accountants. Auditors only need to confirm that specified procedures were followed without having to express an opinion about the accuracy of the information being transmitted. Standard-setting agents know very well that such safe-harbour loopholes limit accountants’ professional obligations, and their exposure to both reputational damage and civil and criminal penalties. Corporate fraud, bribery and illegal- gratuity statutes limit this exposure even further by setting hard-to-prove standards for punishing deceitful reporting. Persuading accountants to certify misleading reports proved to be easy in scandalous cases such as Enron. The greater scandal is the survival of safe-harbour loopholes and the difficulty of assembling evidence that can prove auditor or rating-agency malfeasance. These phenomena testify to the effectiveness of these professions’ lobbies and to the strength of the incentive conflicts these lobbies transmit to government officials. Sooner or later, the practical ethics of the accounting and credit-rating professions must make their members more energetically embrace their twin common-law duties of rejecting corrupting forms of compensation and assuring the economic meaningfulness of the income and net-worth figures their clients publish. Download 1.95 Mb. Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: |
Ma'lumotlar bazasi mualliflik huquqi bilan himoyalangan ©fayllar.org 2024
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling