Centre for Economic Policy Research
Download 1.95 Mb. Pdf ko'rish
|
geneva5
Discussion and Roundtables 91
Ernst-Ludwig von Thadden University of Lausanne Ernst-Ludwig von Thadden, praising the Report for an impressive blend of practitioner and academic insights, focused his discussion on the audit side which is mostly concerned with the problem of accounting, and less on the rating side. As an example of what accounting is about, he quoted from Enron’s Risk Management Manual: ‘Reported earnings follow the rules and principles of accounting. The results do not always create measures consistent with underlying economics. However, corporate management’s performance is generally measured by accounting income, not underlying economics. Risk management strategies are therefore directed at accounting rather than economic performance’. What are, then, the incentives of accounting? According to the Report, the recent accounting scandals have brought to the fore three aspects. First comes the distinction between rules-based and principles- based accounting. The former allows the auditor to hide behind formalities. In a society that puts a strong emphasis on litigation, rules-based accounting may be the best response of the profession. Second, the internal organization of audit firms matters. The argument, not often made in this context, is that decentraliza- tion forces local offices to accommodate local monopolists. This is highly similar to what in banking is called concentration risk. The last component of scandals is the governance of the firm-auditor relationship. Auditors who are hired and remunerated by management instead of the board have the wrong loyalties. Von Thadden said that these points are well-taken but more interesting is that the Report exonerates two of the most publicly accused culprits. The first is the decay of ethical standards, and the second is the provision of non-audit consulting services by audit firms. He fully agreed with the report on the first point, arguing that ethical decay is typically too easily invoked and too little quantified. He pointed out, however, that the second issue might deserve more attention. The authors exonerate service bundling because of the opportunity cost of separating audit and non-audit services. Yet the authors are silent about the potential costs arising from the bundling of these two services. In fact, the ‘dependency or conflict’ may depend precisely on the ‘question of what service is performed’. So the two activities cannot be as easily separated as suggested by the Report. Von Thadden proposed to make his point with a little thought experiment of what the auditing industry might be about. Consider a firm that may be either well managed (IBM) or mismanaged (Enron). Call this state, with proba(x=1)=q. An auditor exerts effort to find out about x. Given their effort, they learn about x through a signal which is such that Once the auditor has observed s, they announce their audit that is either bad or good, . In the long run, the state of the firm, x, is revealed publicly. The auditor’s objective is p(x,a), reflecting the potential trade-off between having a good reputation and being on good terms with management. In particular, we have with p(0,g) and p(0,b) in between. p(1,b) is what you get if the firm is good and you state that it is bad. This is the worst thing that can hap- pen to an auditor. He is getting on bad terms with the management and he is los- ing his reputation for being a good forecaster. On the other hand, p(1,g) is the best that can happen to an auditor because he is having the right forecast and being on good terms with the management. p(0,g) and p(0,b) are in between. If the firm is bad and the auditor is making a 92 Conflicts of Interest in the Financial Services Industry } 1 , 0 { ∈ x ] 1 , 2 / 1 [ ∈ e } 1 , 0 { ∈ s e x s proba x s proba = = = = = = ) 0 0 ( ) 1 1 ( } , { g b a ∈ ) , 1 ( ) , 1 ( g p b p << good forecast, that is p(0, g), the auditor is on good terms with management but since the forecast is wrong, that may be bad for his reputation. p(0,b) is the other way around; the auditor makes the right forecast but the management does not like it. How to solve this? The auditor has two possible strategies for her reporting: (strategy H being the honest strategy): Strategy H: a(0) = b, a(1) = g Strategy A: a(0) = a(1) = g A simple comparison shows that strategy H yields more than strategy A if and only if: (1-q)ep(0,b) + q(1-e)p(1,b) > (1-q)ep(0,g) + q(1-e)p(1,g) This is likely to be the case if: • p(0,g) and p(1,g) are small: gains from the firm-auditor relationship are not too large. • e is large: auditors monitor carefully. • p(0,b) is large: high professional standards in auditing. If these conditions do not hold, the auditor is likely to fall into the ‘Andersen trap’, namely, provide favourable audit opinions when it is not justified by the data. Of course, this is just a very simple example; but it is not grossly implausible and describes a situation in which the ‘dependency or conflict’ depends precisely on the ‘question of what service is performed’. Von Thadden’s overall conclusion was that although there are reasons to believe that the Sarbanes-Oxley Act is a case of premature and half-baked legislation, the argument against it in the present report needs to be strengthened. Download 1.95 Mb. Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: |
Ma'lumotlar bazasi mualliflik huquqi bilan himoyalangan ©fayllar.org 2024
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling