Economic Geography
Download 3.2 Kb. Pdf ko'rish
|
Economic and social geography
Conclusions
For much of its history, economic geography has been preoccupied with where commodities are produced, where they are traded, and where they are consumed. This kind of logic can be found in textbooks, in past and in current research, and in a barely articulated world-view that joins us together as a field of academic research and practice. Of course, commodities matter. This kind of reference point provides us a means of understanding where people live and work and how they joined together in institutions of action and negotiation. But for too long this kind of recipe for research has been blind to the role and significance of global financial markets, the rules of investment, and the imperatives behind successive waves of industrial and regional restructuring (Christopherson 2002). Just as geography matters, finance matters! One of the unfortunate consequences of a single-minded focus upon the sites of production has been an uncritical commitment to describing the landscape in terms of its particularities as if each and every region is its own ensemble of untraded interdependencies. This has led us down a path that has been joined by other disciplines such as political science and sociology similarly committed to understanding capitalism in terms of its variety rather than its commonalities (see Hall and Soskice 2001 and compare with Strange 1997). In my own research, I have made contributions to this theme albeit in the shadows cast by the world of finance and its arbitrage processes (see, for example Clark 1989). My objection to this kind of research is not an objection to the fine-grained case studies that are so informative about the geography of production. My objection is to claims that the best economic geography is that which begins with local units, with production, and with a commitment to path dependence. Finance is all about pricing and trading in and out of path dependence, whatever its jurisdiction, and whatever it special circumstances. We might object to this fact of life, but we should do so in terms of its social consequences (Clark and Wójcik 2007). The world of finance seems very different to that which we inherited. It has a different language, dictionaries of terms and concepts that seem, at first light, to be quite foreign (Clark et al. 2006). But as I have shown in this chapter, the diction- aries of terms are subject to their own internal tensions. Furthermore, the tensions between the theory and practice of finance provides us a way of understanding the processes that promise to remake the global economic landscape over the twenty- first century. We should be part of understanding global finance, its markets, and its social and economic processes. At the same time, as is the case in all social science disciplines, we have an obligation to build holistic models of the whole world. Download 3.2 Kb. Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: |
Ma'lumotlar bazasi mualliflik huquqi bilan himoyalangan ©fayllar.org 2024
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling