Harald Heinrichs · Pim Martens Gerd Michelsen · Arnim Wiek Editors
Overcoming the Controversy Between Neoclassical
Download 5.3 Mb. Pdf ko'rish
|
core text sustainability
4
Overcoming the Controversy Between Neoclassical and Ecological Economics The two approaches of weak and strong sustainability still stand in opposition to each other. Efforts were made relatively early to bridge the differences in the con- trary positions. The contributions of Steurer ( 2001 ), for example, deserve mention (von Hauff and Jörg 2013 , p. 130ff). This effort also includes the concept of “sus- tainable economics” as presented, for example, by Rogall ( 2012 , p. 190). However, these approaches do not by any means present a uniform position. For example, while Steurer promotes strong sustainability, Hedinger tends to focus on weak sus- tainability. The approaches nevertheless combine the strengths of both concepts. In this respect, it is appropriate to return to the category of vital natural capital. As already established in the two-step sustainability rule, there is no substitute for essential natural capital and it must not be endangered. On the other hand, the sub- stitution of nonessential natural capital is permitted. The problem, as has already been mentioned, is in defi ning acceptable limits on the use of essential natural capi- tal. The issue involves accounting for the unpredictability and risk, which is not always clear or easy to defi ne. At a minimum, an intact ecosystem multiplies the prosperity of humans and is therefore indispensable. Sometimes real and natural capital are substitutable and, in other cases, complementary. If this insight is applied to the central point of the con- troversy between neoclassical economics and ecological economics, the following becomes evident: Neither a general halt to growth (ecological economy) nor infi nite quantitative growth (neoclassical economy) seems to be warranted. Pearce claims that growth, in addition to the many positive effects like the strengthening of the social security systems, stabilization of the labor markets, and the increase in gov- ernment revenues with the associated greater scope for government expenditures on things like education and research, also facilitates efforts to preserve the environ- ment for motivational, structural, and fi nancial reasons (Pearce 1991 , p. 11). Through improved effi ciency, frugality, recycling, structural improvements, and increased use of alternative renewable resources, it must be possible to decouple the two factors of growth and environmental quality from one another. Decoupling, for example, may refer to a rising GDP and a lowering of emissions. In this case, a clear target for the lowering of emissions (absolute decoupling) should be defi ned. The advocates of balanced sustainability promote an economic and ecological optimiza- tion. Balanced sustainability envisions a slowing of growth or a stop to growth solely as a potential result of the ecological restructuring of the society. In effect, the aim is for the harmonization of growth and environmental quality. • Task: Please discuss how the supporters of balanced sustainability integrate the two opposing positions of weak and strong sustainability. Considering some successful examples of the substitution of natural capital with real capital, it does not appear necessary to reject the substitution rule fully. There are some situations in which real capital can be substituted for natural capital (e.g., cultivated, managed forests). However, the idea of unlimited substitution, as 8 Sustainable Development in Economics 106 is permitted in the framework of weak sustainability, does not support the require- ment for intergenerational equity. This is predicated on the unpredictable risk asso- ciated with the rising consumption of essential natural capital. It can be assumed that technological progress will continue in the future, and new alternatives for the substitution of natural resources will be found. Nevertheless, there is no reason to assume with any regularity that technological innovation will be in a fundamental position to fully and equivalently replace natural capital. Consequently, every ecological function must have an “artifi cial substitute.” For example, to substitute a forested area, fully equivalent functions must be provided. There can be no downside to the substitute that was not also present in the original (von Hauff and Jörg 2013 , p. 131). The substitute must verifi ably exist and not just be promised in the “escape avenues of technological daydreams” (Ott and Döring 2008 , p. 156). If happiness and moral values are included in the equation, it may be assumed that future generations may not even want the substitution of nature. With that in mind, it can be said that strong sustainability leaves open more options than weak sustainability, and it gives future generations more “freedom to choose.” In summary, balanced sustainability takes on a mediating role in this debate, in which not only a constant total stock of capital, but, because of the limited substitut- ability of natural capital, many of the essential components of natural capital (cli- mate balance, global life cycles, ozone layer, and balanced ecological system like forests, lakes and rivers, biodiversity, etc.) must also be maintained at a constant level. The maintenance of a minimum reserve is proposed for less vital stocks (Pearce 1991 ). It must also be acknowledged in this context that not all of the rele- vant information necessary to facilitate the identifi cation and defi nition of clear lim- its on essential natural capital is available. Download 5.3 Mb. Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: |
Ma'lumotlar bazasi mualliflik huquqi bilan himoyalangan ©fayllar.org 2024
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling