The Physics of Wall Street: a brief History of Predicting the Unpredictable
Download 3.76 Kb. Pdf ko'rish
|
6408d7cd421a4-the-physics-of-wall-street
A New Manhattan Project
• 201 their own) would retire, and the costs of providing them with benefits would rapidly outstrip the program’s ability to fund itself. And yet, there was little to be done. for a politician to draw attention to Social Security’s woes was suicidal. the two obvious solutions to the funding problem — reducing benefits and raising taxes — were equally unappealing. Social Security presented a kind of political catch-22 — that is, until daniel Patrick Moynihan and Bob Packwood, the two leading members of the Senate finance committee in the mid-nine- ties, shared a moment of inspiration. If you wanted to come up with $1 trillion without anyone noticing the difference, all you needed to do was change the value of money. Here’s how the plan worked. Projections for the future costs of So- cial Security were based on the expected rate of inflation, which in turn was based on the cPI. Moynihan and Packwood realized that if the official rate of inflation could be lowered, the income from the Social Security tax would rise, and the costs of administering the pro- gram would fall. the effect would be to raise taxes and reduce entitle- ments, relative to the real buying power of money, without acknowl- edging that you were doing so. the challenge was to find an argument for why inflation calculations should be modified. this is where the Boskin commission came in. It was a masterful sleight of hand. Work- ing backward from the figure of $1 trillion, which Moynihan believed would be necessary to keep Social Security solvent, he and Packwood determined that inflation would need to be reduced by 1.1%. According to notes written by robert Gordon, an economist at northwestern University and one of the five members of the com- mission, dale Jorgenson — the Harvard economist who had thrown Malaney out of his office — reported to the commission early on that they were aiming for $1 trillion in Social Security savings over ten years, and that this meant they needed to come up with the requisite reduction in inflation. then the committee broke up into two teams to work on different ways in which the problems of changing preferences and changing quality could affect cPI. Gordon and the other person on his team, working together, arrived at one number. the other team, which included Jorgenson and Boskin, arrived at another. And then, “somehow” (Gordon’s word), when the two teams combined their re- sults, the commission’s final recommendation “corrected” inflation by precisely 1.1%. the Boskin commission’s findings were criticized from all cor- ners. As Gordon later reported, the project was rushed and careless. He and his collaborator finished their contribution days before the commission was due to present to the Senate. the calculations were what physicists and economists both call “back of the envelope,” little more than informal estimates. the commission’s report was never peer-reviewed before it was presented to the Senate. none of the other members of the commission ever asked how his team had come up with their number, or how the others had arrived at theirs. the answer to such questions would have inconvenient. (Ultimately, many of the Boskin commission’s recommendations were squashed by effective lobbying on the part of the AArP and others; about five years later, the national Academy of Sciences and the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statis- tics returned to the problem of how to calculate the cPI, with a more intellectually rigorous approach, and with more nuanced findings.) Malaney approached Jorgenson with her and Weinstein’s ideas about index numbers soon after the Boskin commission was formed. Jorgenson may have had deep criticisms of Malaney and Weinstein’s proposal. they may have even been good criticisms. But it is hard to avoid guessing that it would have caused problems for the Boskin commission had a new and mathematically rigorous method emerged for calculating precisely what they were tasked to calculate. It seems the easiest thing was to make Malaney and Weinstein go away. exporting gauge theories, or other ideas from physics, to econom- ics remains a hard sell. Weinstein was right that late 2008 presented a unique opportunity for someone inclined to change the way econ- omists thought about the world — and the world, economics. Many people in finance, in economics, and in ordinary homes around the world were scared. things that many people thought they understood turned out to be changing and unreliable. Meanwhile, people working in other fields, such as physics and mathematics, saw an opportunity to contribute to a field that seemed besieged. the suggestion that it was time to reevaluate some of the principal theories and methods of 202 • t h e p h y s i c s o f wa l l s t r e e t A New Manhattan Project • 203 modern economics struck a chord with many, including Smolin and a handful of other physicists working at Perimeter. Smolin, who previously had been reading up on economics in his spare time, began to consider working on it more seriously. He col- lected notes he had written on various topics, including his take on Weinstein and Malaney’s proposal, and put them together in a paper that he then posted on an online archive where physicists post new research. the paper was a kind of translation dictionary, explaining basic economics to physicists and then showing how ideas that physi- cists were already comfortable with could be applied to this otherwise foreign science. Meanwhile, Smolin and Weinstein began organizing a conference to be held at Perimeter. It was scheduled for May 2009. the plan was to invite representatives from across the spectrum of economics, with a goal of bringing together a diverse and heterodox group of people to discuss how to move the field forward in light of the recent crisis. Weinstein and Smolin participated, but so did others, such as doyne farmer and emanuel derman. Mainstream economists were also in- vited, such as nouriel roubini of new York University, Barkley rosser of James Madison University, and richard freeman of Harvard, as well as nassim taleb. richard Alexander, a well-known evolutionary biologist, was invited to describe how biology and human behavior could inform economics. the plan was simple. Get a large group of smart people in a room, get them all to see that economics had clear problems, and convince them to work together to come up with a new theory. the plan was to use this conference to kick off the new Man- hattan Project. the conference itself was a success: this wide-ranging group of physicists, biologists, economists, and finance professionals found much to debate and discuss. But when the conference ended, the re- searchers went their separate ways. As Smolin later explained, there was too much bullheadedness even among these economics outsid- ers to produce fruitful collaboration. everyone agreed that economic theory faced major problems, but it was impossible to build consensus on what the problems were, never mind how to fix them. Many of the Download 3.76 Kb. Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: |
Ma'lumotlar bazasi mualliflik huquqi bilan himoyalangan ©fayllar.org 2024
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling