The Physics of Wall Street: a brief History of Predicting the Unpredictable
Download 3.76 Kb. Pdf ko'rish
|
6408d7cd421a4-the-physics-of-wall-street
Swimming Upstream
• 45 revolutionize financial markets. Still, his work did not make the splash on Wall Street that more developed versions of his ideas would, in the hands of other researchers just a short time later. osborne was a tran- sitional figure. He was read widely by academics and some theoreti- cally minded practitioners, but Wall Street was not yet ready to move firmly in the direction that osborne’s work suggested. In part the diffi- culty was that osborne believed that his model of market randomness implied that it was impossible to predict how individual stock prices would change with time; unlike Bachelier, osborne didn’t connect his work to options, where understanding the statistical properties of markets can help you identify when options are correctly priced. In- deed, reading “Brownian Motion in the Stock Market” and osborne’s later work, one gets the sense that there is no way to profit from the stock market. Prices are unpredictable. the speculator’s average gain is zero. Investing is a losing proposition. Later, people would look at osborne’s work and see something more optimistic. If you know that stock prices are essentially random, then, as Bachelier pointed out, you can figure out the value of options or other derivatives based on those stocks. osborne didn’t take his work in this direction — at least, not until the late 1970s, when others had already made similar moves. Instead, he spent much of the rest of his career trying to figure out the ways in which stock prices aren’t random. In other words, after tying himself to the enormously con- troversial claim that stock prices represent “unrelieved bedlam” (his words, in many of his articles), osborne systematically and exhaus- tively searched for order and predictability. He had some limited success. He showed that the volume of trad- ing — the number of trades that take place in any given stretch of time — isn’t constant, as one would naively assume in a Brownian motion model. Instead, there are peaks in volume at the beginning and end of a trading day, over the course of an average trading week, and over the course of a month. (All of these variations, incidentally, represent just the kind of “slow fluctuations” osborne had explored with his migra- tory salmon — applied not to prices, but to numbers of trades.) these variations arise from what osborne took to be another principle of market psychology, that investors have limited attention spans. they get interested in a stock, they make a lot of trades and send the volume of trades way up, and then they gradually stop paying attention and volume decreases. If you allow for variations in volume, you have to change the underlying assumptions of the random walk model, and you get a new, more accurate model of how stock prices evolve, which osborne called the “extended Brownian motion” model. In the mid-sixties, osborne and a collaborator showed that at any instant, the chances that a stock will go up are not necessarily the same as the chances that the stock will go down. this assumption, you’ll re- call, was an essential part of the Brownian motion model, where a step in one direction is assumed to be just as likely as a step in the other. osborne showed that if a stock went up a little bit, its next motion was much more likely to be a move back down than another move up. Likewise, if a stock went down, it was much more likely to go up in value in its next change. that is, from moment to moment the market is much more likely to reverse itself than to continue on a trend. But there was another side to this coin. If a stock moved in the same direc- tion twice, it was much more likely to continue in that direction than if it had moved in a given direction only once. osborne argued that the infrastructure of the trading floor was responsible for this kind of non- randomness, and osborne went on to suggest a model for how prices change that took this kind of behavior into account. this was a hallmark of osborne’s work, and it was one of the rea- sons he’s such an important figure in the story of physics and finance. the idea that prices are equally likely to move up or down was part of osborne’s version of the efficient market hypothesis, a central assump- tion of his original model. When he realized this assumption didn’t hold, he began to look for ways to tweak the model to account for a more realistic assumption, based on what he had learned about real markets. osborne was explicit from the beginning that this was his methodology, in keeping with the kinds of theoretical work he was familiar with in astronomy and fluid dynamics. In those fields, most problems are much too hard to solve all at once. Instead, you begin by studying the data and then make simplifying assumptions to derive simple models. But this is only the first step. next, you check carefully 46 • t h e p h y s i c s o f wa l l s t r e e t |
Ma'lumotlar bazasi mualliflik huquqi bilan himoyalangan ©fayllar.org 2024
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling