The Physics of Wall Street: a brief History of Predicting the Unpredictable
Download 3.76 Kb. Pdf ko'rish
|
6408d7cd421a4-the-physics-of-wall-street
Physics Hits the Street
• 113 to control risk. the difference was that thorp’s delta hedge strategy aimed to guarantee a profit, provided that the underlying stock’s price didn’t change too dramatically. this approach controlled risk, but it didn’t eliminate it altogether. (Indeed, if cAPM-style reasoning is cor- rect, you shouldn’t be able to both eliminate risk and still make a sub- stantial profit.) Black’s approach was to find a portfolio consisting of stocks and options that was risk-free, and then argue by cAPM rea- soning that this portfolio should be expected to earn the risk-free rate of return. Black’s strategy of building a risk-free asset from stocks and options is now called dynamic hedging. Black had read cootner’s collection of essays on the randomness of markets, and so he was familiar with Bachelier’s and osborne’s work on the random walk hypothesis. this gave him a way to model how the underlying stock prices changed over time — which in turn gave him a way to understand how options prices must change over time, given the link he had discovered between options prices and stock prices. once Black had found this fundamental relationship between the price of a stock, the price of an option on that stock, and the risk- free interest rate, it was just a few steps of algebra for him to derive an equation for the value of the option, by relating the risk premium on the stock to the risk premium on the option. But now he was stuck. the equation he derived was a complicated differential equation — an equation relating the instantaneous rate of change of the price of the option to the instantaneous rate of change of the price of the stock — and Black, despite his background in physics and mathematics, didn’t know enough math to solve it. After struggling for several months, Black gave up. He didn’t tell anyone about the options problem, or his partial solution, until later in 1969, when Scholes mentioned that one of his master’s students at MIt was interested in options pricing. Scholes began to speculate about whether cAPM could be used to solve the problem — at which point Black opened his desk drawer and pulled out a sheet of paper with the crucial differential equation written on it, and from then on the two men worked on the problem together. they had solved it by summer 1970, and the Black-Scholes equation for the price of an option made its debut in July, at a conference that Scholes organized at MIt, spon- sored by Wells fargo. In the meantime, a new colleague of Scholes’s at MIt, robert Merton (himself an engineer by training, though he went on to earn a Phd in economics), had rederived the same differential equation and the same solution from an entirely different starting point. With two different approaches giving the same answer, Black, Scholes, and Merton were convinced they were on to something big. Black and Scholes submitted their paper to the Journal of Political Economy, one of the most important publications in the field, soon after they had solved the problem. the paper was promptly rejected, without so much as a note of explanation (suggesting it wasn’t even seriously considered). So they tried again, this time with Review of Economics and Statistics. Again, they received a rapid rejection with no articulation of what was wrong with the article. Merton, meanwhile, held off on sending his alternative approach to journals, so that Black and Scholes could receive appropriate credit for their discovery. despite the early setbacks, however, Black and Scholes were not destined to labor in obscurity. Powerful forces in academia, in finance, and in politics were aligning in their favor. And some of the then- reigning academic gods were ready to intervene. After the second re- jection, University of chicago professors eugene fama and Merton Miller, two of the most influential economists at the time and leaders of the then-nascent chicago School of economics, successfully urged the Journal of Political Economy to reconsider, and in August 1971 the article was accepted for publication, pending revisions. In the meantime, fischer Black had attracted attention at the Uni- versity of chicago. economists there were familiar with his work with Scholes, both on options and at Wells fargo; they’d seen him in ac- tion at the Wells fargo conference. A few years earlier, in 1967, Black had traveled to chicago with treynor to present some of their collab- orative work to the graybeards. chicago economists didn’t need fancy journals to vet young academics: they knew talent when they saw it, and Black certainly had talent. And so in May 1971, they offered Black a job. At this point, Black had already been out of graduate school for seven years, yet he had only four publications, just two of which were 114 • t h e p h y s i c s o f wa l l s t r e e t |
Ma'lumotlar bazasi mualliflik huquqi bilan himoyalangan ©fayllar.org 2024
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling