13
institutions exist and are more effective at risk-bearing than the government.
17
These
deliberations should take into account the possibility of “inefficient” government
interventions due to political pressures and constraints, and “government failure” (see
Stiglitz, 1993).
One general principle for risk-taking decisions in the context of the institutional
analysis above is that risks should be borne by those better able to control their source
and for whom the protection against risk is least costly. The rationale for this lies in the
need to reduce moral hazard behavior, by giving incentives to those who
can mitigate risk to
do so. This principle has been used, for example, to support the argument for the U.S.
government’s need to intervene as insurer of last resort against terrorism risk, given that the
government’s actions and the objectives it pursues could influence
the likelihood and
intensity of terrorist threats (III, 2004). In the case of private-public partnership projects,
where risk transfer is fundamental, this principle has generally translated into the transfer to
the private sector of project-specific risks (such as construction,
operating, and
design/technical risks) that it is best placed to manage and the assumption by governments of
economy-wide risks (such as force majeure, regulatory and political risks), although risk
distribution has been rightly approached on a case by case basis given the different nature of
projects (Figure 1 illustrates a rule-of-thumb approach on how risks
could be shared in PPP
arrangements).
18
In cases where neither the public or private partner has an obvious
advantage in managing particular risks (such as demand, financing, and project default risk),
countries have followed different approaches in allocating them. In
some cases, demand risk
was fully transferred to the private partner (toll and shadow toll road concessions common in
Europe), often resulting in subsequent costly renegotiations (Hungarian and Mexican
motorway PPPs; OECD/ITF 2008), while in others demand
risk was retained by the
government, with sometimes costly outcomes for the government (Colombia).
19
Increasingly, therefore, PPP arrangements involve sharing demand risk between the private
and the public sector (Chile, Colombia, Korea).
20
17
Good examples of such an analysis include the study by the United States’ Congressional Budget Office
“Assessing the Public Costs and Benefits of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac” (May 1996) or U.K.’s NERA report
“The Economic Rationale for the Public Provision of Export Credit Insurance by ECGD” (April 2000).
18
For a discussion of the principles underlying risk-sharing arrangements in PPPs see Hemming et al. (2006),
Irwin (2007), OECD/ITF (2008) and OECD (2008).
19
During the 1990s, Colombia’s PPP guarantees involved a significant number
of demand guarantees, several
of which were triggered partly as a result of the recession of the late 1990s, resulting in cumulative payments of
2 percent of GDP by 2004 (Cebotari et al., 2008).
20
Chile, Colombia, and Korea guarantee concessionaire traffic or revenues, but the guarantees are partial and
include features that ensure sharing of both downside and upside risks (OECD/ITF 2008).