Economic Geography
On models, Marxism and men
Download 3.2 Kb. Pdf ko'rish
|
Economic and social geography
On models, Marxism and men
There are several reasons why economic geographers have, by and large, tended to neglect feminist arguments. First, like economics, the discourse and methods of economic geography are highly contested. In the 1960s, the proponents of what was then seen as a revolutionary approach – spatial science – turned against the earlier largely descriptive work on regional development – to argue for an understanding of economic landscapes based in abstract flows, best analysed by mathematical modelling, in which transportation costs and friction of distance loomed large and the resulting spatial patterns might be explained by network algebra. These disembodied, a-historical, placeless explanations had a logical elegance and a conceptual attraction that mirrors neo-classical models in econom- ics but denied the existence of real actors, limited knowledge, vested interest and power. A response to these criticisms lay in the turn to the explanatory power of geo-historical materialism, largely stimulated by David Harvey’s (1973, 1982, 1985, 1989, 1996) work and by others writing outside geography but influencing its debates. Castells’ (1977) work on collective consumption and Lipietz’s (1987) development of regulation theory, for example, had a huge impact on urban and economic geography respectively. Marxism, itself a contested and diverse Feminist economic geographies 35 approach, led to different emphases: on the circulation of capital, on the accu- mulation process, on class divisions and class struggle, providing a welcome correc- tion to some of the absences in neo-classical and modelling approaches. But, of course, each of these approaches depends on an entirely different conception of the world, on an unbridgeable epistemological divide, still reflected in the current divisions between those who draw on versions of political economy and those who have turned to the mathematical elegance of the ‘new economic geography’ with its parallels in economics with the work of inter alia Krugman (1991) and Venables (1998). Secure within their disciplinary camps, few scholars have been prepared to redefine their theoretical or empirical work in the face of feminist critiques. Too much might be lost by giving ground in an academic environment increasingly defined by individualistic notions of competition and success. The second reason why economic geography has been reluctant to embrace feminism is connected to the first: each of the two approaches above neglect gender relations. In the first, people seldom appear at all and in the latter, when they do figure, they are ungendered capitalists, entrepreneurs, financiers or work- ers and class struggle is seen as the motor of resistance. In both Castells’s and Lipietz’s work, for example, women’s unpaid domestic labours are excluded: in the former by Castells’s definition of collective consumption – the provision by the state of the services necessary to reproduce the working class – and in the latter the exclusion of women and the home from the social relations of capitalism erased the family and the home and its division of labour from examination (see McDowell 1991). But the reasons for this neglect lie deeper in the structure of modern social thought and its distinction between the public highly regulated worlds of the economy and polity, of government, labour markets, trade and commerce and the private world of the home, constructed as a space of leisure and affection, unreg- ulated and largely untouched by the competitive world of industrial capitalism, at least as an ideal, if seldom in practice. This division, as many feminist scholars have argued, is one that is paralleled by a gender division – the public world is a world of men, the private world that of women, based on ‘natural’ associations of love and care, untainted by the cash nexus. Its very naturalness needs no theo- retical explanation. Here too there is a well-known critique, now generally uncontested but still ignored in ‘mainstream’ work. Feminist economists and geographers, however, have carefully explored the reasons for and the consequences of the absence of the private worlds of domestic labour, reproduction, caring for others, from the very definition of what is ‘economic’ and what activities constitute the ‘economy’ (Massey 1997; McDowell 1999, 2000a). Despite these arguments, some of the most thoughtful economic geographers writing today – often precisely on the contested definition of the economic (Castree 2004; Hudson 2004) and/or on the changing nature of work (Castree et al. 2004) – still ignore the gendered construction of these concepts, so neglecting large areas of unpaid and voluntary labour, largely undertaken by women. Despite the continued neglect of these theoretical arguments by too many economic geographers, the material world has changed in recent decades in ways 36 Download 3.2 Kb. Do'stlaringiz bilan baham: |
Ma'lumotlar bazasi mualliflik huquqi bilan himoyalangan ©fayllar.org 2024
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling