The Physics of Wall Street: a brief History of Predicting the Unpredictable
Download 3.76 Kb. Pdf ko'rish
|
6408d7cd421a4-the-physics-of-wall-street
Physics Hits the Street
• 123 change. Beginning with the carter administration in the late 1970s, the U.S. economy entered a period of high inflation and low growth that has subsequently been dubbed “stagflation.” In response, Paul volcker, the chairman of the federal reserve from 1979 through 1987, increased interest rates dramatically, so that the prime interest rate, the rate that determines how expensive it is for banks to lend to one another — and, by extension, to lend to consumers — reached an unprecedented level of 21.5%. volcker was successful at reducing inflation, which he had under control by 1983. But this volatility in interest rates forever changed the previously sleepy bond industry. If banks couldn’t borrow from one another for less than 20%, surely corporations and govern- ments that were trying to issue bonds would need to pay even higher rates (since typically bonds are more risky than interbank loans). the so-called bond bores of the 1970s, traders who had chosen to work in the least exciting of the financial markets, now needed to cope with the most variable market of all. (Sherman Mccoy, the star-crossed anti- hero of thomas Wolf’s novel Bonfire of the Vanities, was an eighties-era bond trader who took himself to be so important, given the changes in the bond markets during the late seventies and early eighties, that he privately called himself a “Master of the Universe.” the name has stuck, now used to refer to Wall Street traders of all stripes.) the success of the Black-Scholes model and other derivatives mod- els during the 1970s inspired some economists to ask whether bonds could be modeled in a similar way to options. Soon, Black and oth- ers had realized that bonds themselves could be thought of as simple derivatives, with interest rates as the underlying asset. they began to develop modified versions of the Black-Scholes model to price bonds, based on the hypothesis that interest rates undergo a random walk. thus, Black arrived on Wall Street at a moment when derivatives, and derivative models, were proving increasingly important, in unex- pected ways. Black’s Quantitative Strategies Group at Goldman Sachs, as well as similar groups at other major banks, provided an answer to questions that many investment bankers, and especially bond traders, hadn’t known how to ask. At the same time, there was a large pool of underemployed physicists who were ready to step in and follow Black’s lead in changing financial practice. once a few physicists and half- physicists had made their way to Wall Street, and once the usefulness of the ideas that Black had managed to translate from theory to prac- tice was appreciated, the floodgates opened. Wall Street began hiring physicists by the hundreds. derman stayed at Bell Labs for five years. Starting in 1983, though, he began to get phone calls from headhunters sent from investment banks. He was unhappy enough at Bell Labs that he took these offers seriously, but when he finally received an offer from Goldman Sachs, he declined it on the advice of an acquaintance who had worked there before. But the world was changing. derman found the next year at Bell Labs intolerable, and so when Wall Street came calling again, in 1985, he was ready to move. He decided to go with Goldman Sachs after all, and in december of 1985 he made the leap. His job was in the financial Services Group, which supported Goldman’s bond traders. By the time he arrived, Black was already an institutional legend. Both thorp and Black based their options models on osborne’s ran- dom walk hypothesis, which amounted to assuming that rates of re- turn are normally distributed. this might give you pause. After all, Mandelbrot argued throughout the 1960s that normal and log-nor- mal distributions do not effectively account for extreme events, that markets are wildly random. even if Mandelbrot’s claim that rates of return are Lévy-stable distributed and thus do not have well-defined volatility is false — and most economists now believe it is — the weaker claim that market data exhibit fat tails still holds. options models as- sign prices based on the probability that a stock will rise above (or drop below) a certain threshold — namely, the strike price for the op- tion. If extreme market changes are more likely than osborne’s model predicts, neither thorp’s model nor the Black-Scholes model will get options prices right. In particular, they should undervalue options that would be exercised only if the market makes a dramatic move, so- called far-out-of-the-money options. A more realistic options model, meanwhile, should account for fat tails. Mandelbrot left finance at the end of the 1960s, but he returned in the early 1990s. one of the reasons was that many financial practi- tioners were beginning to recognize the shortcomings of the Black- 124 • t h e p h y s i c s o f wa l l s t r e e t |
Ma'lumotlar bazasi mualliflik huquqi bilan himoyalangan ©fayllar.org 2024
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling
ma'muriyatiga murojaat qiling